Tax Incremental Financing (TIF) is part of the new mall-project's funding source for "reclaiming" the streets lost to downtown Burlington during Urban Renewal. Burlington voters will be asked to vote on using $22 million in TIF funds to finance the rebuilding of streets that will serve to improve Don Sinex's development project and increase his income. Because of the way TIF works, a large proportion of tax revenue generated by a new project (in this case 75%) has to go to paying back the TIF loan over a period of 20 or 30 years, leaving only 25% to pay for expensive infrastructure costs (which may not be enough for a project of this scale). But what is TIF and why do some people see it as free money while others see it as a dangerous gamble (it has been outlawed in California!)? The following is excerpted from an article called "Tax Incremental Financing: A Bad Bargain for Tax Payers," by Daniel McGraw, published on a site called Reclaim Democracy: Restoring Citizen Authority Over Corporations:
TIFs have been around for more than 50 years, but only recently have
they assumed such importance. At a time when local governments’ efforts
to foster development, from direct subsidies to the use of eminent
domain to seize property for private development, are already out of
control, TIFs only add to the problem: Although politicians portray TIFs
as a great way to boost the local economy, there are hidden costs they
don’t want taxpayers to know about. Cities generally assume they are not
really giving anything up because the forgone tax revenue would not
have been available in the absence of the development generated by the
TIF. That assumption is often wrong.
“There is always this expectation with TIFs that the economic growth
is a way to create jobs and grow the economy, but then push the costs
across the public spectrum,” says Greg LeRoy, author of The Great American Jobs Scam: Corporate Tax Dodging and the Myth of Job Creation.
“But what is missing here is that the cost of developing private
business has some public costs. Road and sewers and schools are public
costs that come from growth.” Unless spending is cut—and if a TIF really
does generate economic growth, spending is likely to rise, as the local
population grows—the burden of paying for these services will be
shifted to other taxpayers. Adding insult to injury, those taxpayers may
include small businesses facing competition from well-connected chains
that enjoy TIF-related tax breaks. In effect, a TIF subsidizes big
businesses at the expense of less politically influential competitors
and ordinary citizens.
“The original concept of TIFs was to help blighted areas come out of
the doldrums and get some economic development they wouldn’t [otherwise]
have a chance of getting,” says former Fort Worth City Councilman Clyde
Picht, who voted against the Cabela’s TIF. “Everyone probably gets a
big laugh out of their claim that they will draw more tourists than the
Alamo. But what is worse, and not talked about too much, is the shift of
taxes being paid from wealthy corporations to small businesses and
regular people.
“If you own a mom-and-pop store that sells fishing rods and hunting
gear in Fort Worth, you’re still paying all your taxes, and the city is
giving tax breaks to Cabela’s that could put you out of business,” Picht
explains. “The rest of us pay taxes for normal services like public
safety, building inspections, and street maintenance, and those services
come out of the general fund. And as the cost of services goes up, and
the money from the general fund is given to these businesses through a
TIF, the tax burden gets shifted to the regular slobs who don’t have the
same political clout. It’s a crummy way to treat your taxpaying,
law-abiding citizens.”
Almost every state has a TIF law, and the details vary from
jurisdiction to jurisdiction. But most TIFs share the same general
characteristics. After a local government has designated a TIF district,
property taxes (and sometimes sales taxes) from the area are divided
into two streams. The first tax stream is based on the original assessed
value of the property before any redevelopment; the city, county,
school district, or other taxing body still gets that money. The second
stream is the additional tax money generated after development takes
place and the property values are higher. Typically that revenue is used
to pay off municipal bonds that raise money for infrastructure
improvements in the TIF district, for land acquisition through eminent
domain, or for direct payments to a private developer for site
preparation and construction. The length of time the taxes are diverted
to pay for the bonds can be anywhere from seven to 30 years.
Local governments sell the TIF concept to the public by claiming they
are using funds that would not have been generated without the TIF
district. If the land was valued at $10 million before TIF-associated
development and is worth $50 million afterward, the argument goes, the
$40 million increase in tax value can be used to retire the bonds. Local
governments also like to point out that the TIF district may increase
nearby economic activity, which will be taxed at full value.
So, in the case of Cabela’s in Fort Worth, the TIF district was
created to build roads and sewers and water systems, to move streams and
a lake to make the property habitable, and to help defray construction
costs for the company. Cabela’s likes this deal because the money comes
upfront, without any interest. Their taxes are frozen, and the bonds are
paid off by what would have gone into city coffers. In effect, the city
is trading future tax income for a present benefit.
But even if the dedicated tax money from a TIF district suffices to
pay off the bonds, that doesn’t mean the arrangement is cost-free. “TIFs
are being pushed out there right now based upon the ‘but for’ test,”
says Greg LeRoy. “What cities are saying is that no development would
take place but for the TIF.…The average public official says this is
free money, because it wouldn’t happen otherwise. But when you see how
it plays out, the whole premise of TIFs begins to crumble.” Rather than
spurring development, LeRoy argues, TIFs “move some economic development
from one part of a city to another.”
Development Would Have Occurred Anyway
Local officials usually do not consider how much growth might
occur without a TIF. In 2002 the Neighborhood Capital Budget Group
(NCBG), a coalition of 200 Chicago organizations that studies local
public investment, looked at 36 of the city’s TIF districts and found
that property values were rising in all of them during the five years
before they were designated as TIFs. The NCBG projected that the city of
Chicago would capture $1.6 billion in second-stream property tax
revenue—used to pay off the bonds that subsidized private
businesses—over the 23-year life spans of these TIF districts. But it
also found that $1.3 billion of that revenue would have been raised
anyway, assuming the areas continued growing at their pre-TIF rates.
The experience in Chicago is important. The city invested $1.6
billion in TIFs, even though $1.3 billion in economic development would
have occurred anyway. So the bottom line is that the city invested $1.6
billion for $300 million in revenue growth.
The upshot is that TIFs are diverting tax money that otherwise would
have been used for government services. The NCBG study found, for
instance, that the 36 TIF districts would cost Chicago public schools
$632 million (based on development that would have occurred anyway) in
property tax revenue, because the property tax rates are frozen for
schools as well. This doesn’t merely mean that the schools get more
money. If the economic growth occurs with TIFs, that attracts people to
the area and thereby raises enrollments. In that case, the cost of
teaching the new students will be borne by property owners outside the
TIF districts.
Such concerns have had little impact so far, in part because almost
no one has examined how TIFs succeed or fail over the long term. Local
politicians are touting TIFs as a way to promote development, promising
no new taxes, and then setting them up without looking at potential side
effects. It’s hard to discern exactly how many TIFs operate in this
country, since not every state requires their registration. But the
number has expanded exponentially, especially over the past decade.
Illinois, which had one TIF district in 1970, now has 874 (including one
in the town of Wilmington, population 129). A moderate-sized city like
Janesville, Wisconsin—a town of 60,000 about an hour from Madison—has
accumulated 26 TIFs. Delaware and Arizona are the only states without
TIF laws, and most observers expect they will get on board soon.
First used in California in the 1950s, TIFs were supposed to be
another tool, like tax abatement and enterprise zones, that could be
used to promote urban renewal. But cities found they were not very
effective at drawing development into depressed areas. “They had this
tool, but didn’t know what the tool was good for,” says Art Lyons, an
analyst for the Chicago-based Center for Economic Policy Analysis, an
economic think tank that works with community groups. The cities
realized, Lyons theorizes, that if they wanted to use TIFs more, they
had to get out of depressed neighborhoods and into areas with higher
property values, which generate more tax revenue to pay off development
bonds.
The Entire Western World Could Be Blighted
Until the 1990s, most states reserved TIFs for areas that could
be described as “blighted,” based on criteria set forth by statute. But
as with eminent domain, the definition of blight for TIF purposes has
been dramatically expanded. In 1999, for example, Baraboo, Wisconsin,
created a TIF for an industrial park and a Wal-Mart supercenter that
were built on farmland; the blight label was based on a single house in
the district that was uninhabited. In recent years 16 states have
relaxed their TIF criteria to cover affluent areas, “conservation areas”
where blight might occur someday, or “economic development areas,”
loosely defined as commercial or industrial properties.
The result is that a TIF can be put almost anywhere these days. Based
on current criteria, says Jake Haulk, director of the Pittsburgh-based
Allegheny Institute for Public Policy, you could “declare the entire
Western world blighted.”
The rest of the article can be read here: http://reclaimdemocracy.org/tax_increment_financing/
Updates on plans for development of The Pit. Residents are asking Don Sinex to hold genuine public engagement listening sessions at our Neighborhood Planning Assemblies (NPAs) to hear what we want our city to look like, feel like, be like. We want a new green deal from whoever invests in developing The Pit. We want union labor, livable wages that will be a geyser of prosperity for downtown businesses and the tax collector. We can do this together, the Burlington way.
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)
TIF Is a Subsidy to CityPalace Investors
The state's explanation of TIF says: "Current statute requires that the municipality pledge at least 85% of the incremental munic...
-
Brookfield Developer has no plan for public engagement. January 6, 2020, City Council Meeting: Report on City Place project. Complete...
-
Press Release: Coalition for a Livable City Urges Planning Commission to Reject Zoning Change for Cambrian Rise Development From: Coali...
-
Thurs. Jan 30, 2020. Noon and 7pm. Contois Auditorium, City Hall. 60-90 minute presentation to the public about the most recent plan...
No comments:
Post a Comment